Font Size: AAA // Print // Bookmark

Comment for Proposed Rule 75 FR 4143

  • From: Hans Ephraimson
    Organization(s):
    Deutsche Bank

    Comment No: 11713
    Date: 4/22/2010

    Comment Text:

    10-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    DB Commodity Services
    60 Wall Street,
    5
    th
    Floor
    New York, NY 10005
    April 22, 2010
    Via emaih Secretary~CFTC.gov
    David Stawick
    Secretary
    Commodity Futures Trading Commission
    Three Lafayette Center
    1155 21
    st
    Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20581
    Proposed Federal Speculative Position Limits for Referenced Energy Contrac~ :&
    (and Associated Regulations (75 Federal Register 4144 (CFTC, January 26, _2~
    (the "Proposal")
    Dear Mr. Stawick:
    DB Commodity Services LLC ("DBCS"), a Delaware limited liability company that is a
    registered commodity pool operator ("CPO") and commodity trading advisor ("CTA"), welcomes
    the opportunity to submit this letter in response to the Commodity Futures Trading Commission's
    ("Commission" or "CFTC") request for comments in respect of the Proposal. DBCS has been
    registered with the Commission and has been a member of the National Futures Association since
    2005. Its principal place of business is 60 Wall Street, New York, New York 10005, telephone
    number (212) 250-5883. DBCS is a wholly-owned subsidiary ofDB U.S. Financial Markets
    Holding Corporation, which is a wholly-owned, indirect subsidiary of Deutsche Bank AG. DBCS
    currently operates 11 commodity pools traded on NYSE Arca, a national securities exchange, in
    2009 having in the aggregate over 900,000 public investors and approximately $1 lbn in investor
    assets.
    In our comments, Section A offers general remarks, and Section B responds to certain
    questions posed by the Commission.
    A.
    General Comments.
    The futures markets serve a vital role in the health of our economic system: they provide a
    critical price discovery mechanism, enable hedgers to offset risks, allow speculators to express their
    views on price movements in the various futures contracts (whether up or down) and, via passive
    index funds, permit investors to hedge against inflation and diversify their investment portfolios.
    DBCS supports the Commission's efforts to maintain fair and orderly markets. However, DBCS10-002
    C OlvllvINN T
    CL-02713
    evidence or regulatory precedent, is unduly onerous, will significantly limit the usefulness of the
    U.S. futures markets to international traders, and is premature in light of pending congressional
    legislation. 1 As such, the Proposal threatens to undermine the futures markets' advantages listed
    above.
    The Proposal rests on the proposition that increased speculation leads to higher prices and
    volatility, yet provides no evidence for such a link. (In fact, the available evidence supports the
    opposite conclusion.) Second, the proposed regulatory.intrusion into a liquid market is
    unprecedented. Furthermore, because the energy futures market is global, the excessive burden of
    the proposed regulations would, if enacted, drive many investors and traders to foreign exchanges,
    leaving the American markets thinner and therefore less liquid. The Proposal is also unnecessary.
    The nature of the futures markets and the operation of index funds themselves counteract the
    alleged dangers described by the Proposal. Not only are futures markets inherently balanced, but
    index funds help bring about the stability which the Commission seeks to accomplish through
    regulation. Moreover, compliance with the proposed method of account aggregation would be, at
    best, terrifically costly, and, at worst~ impossible for a large financial holding company and its
    affiliates to administer. Finally, it is too early for the Commission to consider the Proposal, as
    legislation is currently pending in Congress to expand the Commission's authority over derivatives
    and impose cross-market position limits over both exchange-traded and over-the-counter
    derivatives.
    2
    (1)The Proposal Lacks an Empirical Basis.
    The assumption behind the proposed position limits is that the growth of commodity index
    funds is directly responsible for inflating prices, thereby creating a "speculative bubble." But the
    available empirical evidence, as compiled and analyzed by CFTC economists, other experts, and
    international regulators, does not support the existence of such a link. In fact, the evidence suggests
    that index fund activity has the opposite effect on the markets. A 2008 study by the CFTC,
    analyzing certain commodities markets over a six-month period from December 31, 2007 to June
    30, 2008, determined that the price of crude oil went
    down
    as index fund activity in energy
    derivatives rose.
    See
    Commodity Futures Trading Commission,
    Commodity Swap Dealers & Index
    Traders with Commission Recommendations
    (Sep. 2008). 3 (This report found the same relationship
    2
    3
    Also, the CFTC may be overstepping its authority by giving notice of these proposed regulations without making a
    specific finding. As the CFTC cites in the Proposal, section 4a(a) of the Commodity Exchange Act (the "Act" or
    "CEA") allows "the Commission, from time to time... [to] proclaim and fix such limits on the amounts of trading
    which may be done or positions which may be held..,
    as the Commission finds are necessary
    to diminish,
    eliminate, or prevent [an undue and unnecessary burden on interstate commerce]." (emphasis added). The Act thus
    requires a specific finding that a rule is "necessary" before it may be proposed. Yet the Proposal does not contain
    such a finding. This omission is not merely a technical violation. Like the futures markets, the CFTC serves a vital
    role in the health of our economic system. But the benefits of this role depend partly on the shared belief among
    regulators, traders, and investors that the CFTC carefully follows fair and longstanding procedures under the
    Administrative Procedure Act of 1946 for the protection of all parties. There is no authority in the CEA for the
    CFTC to impose position limits for the purpose of preventing price movements resulting from large or concentrated
    positions. Taking forceful action in an arbitrary fashion is likely to diminish the general trust in the validity of
    commodity regulations.
    See, e.g.,
    Title III, the Derivatives Markets Transparency and Accountability Act of the Wall Street Reform and
    Consumer Protection Act of 2009, H.R. 4173, 111
    t~
    Congress,
    1
    st
    Session (2009).
    For example, on pages 22-23, the report states:
    While the net notional value of commodity index business in NYMEX WTI crude oil increased sharply over
    the 6-month period ending on June 30, 2008--by about 30 percent, the actual numbers of equivalent long
    2report perceived no clear relationship at all.
    5)
    i0-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    A broader view of the commodities markets bolsters the finding of the CFTC's report. A ¯
    recent analysis based on data from the U.S. Energy Information Administration discovered that
    crude oil prices declined from 2006 to 2008 despite rising index investment.
    See
    Bob Greer,
    Are
    Index Investors Driving Up Commodity Prices?,
    p. 2 (May 2008). A similar conclusion has been
    reached by studies of index funds in the grain markets from 2004 to 2005. Market data for this
    period collected by the CFTC at the behest of the U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee on
    Investigations reveals that price levels remained largely unchanged, despite the dramatic increase in
    index fund positions during the same period.
    See
    Dwight R. Sanders and Scott H. Irwin,
    Bubbles,
    Froth, and Facts: The Impact of Index Funds on Commodity Futures Prices,
    pp. 10-11 (Feb. 2010).
    These results in the energy and grain markets are the converse of what one would expect if
    escalating index investment led to escalating prices.
    6
    As the Chief Economist of the CFTC, Jeffrey
    Harris, testified before the U.S. Senate on May 19, 2008, "The absence of a link between fund
    positions and price changes suggests that global market fundamentals.., provide a better
    explanation for the recent price increase.
    ''7
    International regulators agree with the Chief Economist's interpretation. The Task Force on
    Commodity Futures Markets of the Technical Committee of the International Organization of
    Securities Commissions issued a report in March 2009 ("IOSCO Report"), analyzing the views of
    various global futures regulators. The IOSCO Report found that "the reports reviewed by the Task
    Force do not support the proposition that the activity of speculators has systematically driven
    commodity market cash or futures prices up or down on a sustained basis.
    ''8
    Moreover, neither the business representatives who testified before the CFTC on July 28,
    2009 in favor of stricter position limits nor the Proposal itself have provided the necessary evidence.
    The business representatives offered conjectural statements but no empirical data. They stated, for
    example, as cited in footnote 46 in the Proposal, "This increase in volatility has been
    associated
    with a massive increase in speculative investment in oil futures,
    ''9
    and "Speculative trading
    futures contracts declined over that same period by about 11 percent. In other words, the sharp rise in the net
    notional value of commodity index business in crude oil futures appears to be due to an appreciation of the
    value of existing investments caused by the rise in crude oil prices and not the result of more money flowing
    into commodity index trading. (emphasis in original)
    Id.
    at 27-28.
    Id.
    at 24-25.
    Indeed, as Bob Greer framed the issue on page 4 of his article cited directly above, "If there is any causality, it is
    the other way around. Rising commodity prices have caused an increased interest in commodity investment."
    Jeffrey Harris,
    Written Testimony before the Senate Committee on Homeland Secm'ity and Governmental Affairs
    (May 20, 2008),
    online at
    ~_ac~senate.go_~ublic!index.cfin? FuseAction~ Hearin gs.t tearin~z&Hearin,~+
    ID=31:i~95 f08~0bTd-45d0-94ea
    -
    4c4346c353de.
    Technical Committee of the International Organization of Securities Commissions,
    Task Force on Commodity
    Futures Markets Final Report,
    p. 7 (Mar. 2009),
    online at
    !gt~ :/!www. iosco.org/librar,~2p~.~.~_d_.~_~pdfTiO SCOPD285 opdl:
    Ben Hirst, Senior Vice President and General Counsel for Delta Airlines on behalf of the Air Transport Association
    of America, Inc.,
    Testimony before the Commodity Futures Trading Commission
    (Jul. 28, 2009),
    online at
    h_~) ://www.c~c. goyi~!
    ic/@l~ewsroomidocumer~tsifile/hearin @72809 hirsCpd/'.10-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    CFTC in its Proposal described the ill effects of speculation and concentrated positions as .
    hypothetical: "Large concentrated positions in the energy futures and option markets
    can
    potentially
    facilitate abrupt price movements and price distortions," and "Specifically, when large
    speculative positions are amassed in a contract, or contract month,
    the potential exists
    for
    unreasonable and abrupt price movements should the positions be traded out of or liquidated in a
    disorderly manner." (emphasis added). The possibility of dislocations always exists in any market.
    But the question for the CFTC, as the expert regulator, is not what is possible based on conjecture,
    but what is likely in light of specific findings.
    In sum, it would appear that substantial evidence of a link between speculation and volatility
    or prices does not exist. Not only do theProposal and its supporters fail to offer empirical evidence
    for the Proposal's underlying assumption, but the available evidence supports a contrary
    interpretation.
    (2)The Proposal Lacks Regulatory Precedent.
    No precedent in any commodity futures markets supports the Commission's proposal. The
    Commission's and the contract markets' position limit hedge exemption regimes have always
    allowed a single market participant to establish speculative positions up to the applicable position
    limits but also to obtain hedge exemptions, if the trading warrants it, for hedging positions above
    these levels. There is no reported history of market abuses that warrants the Commission's
    dramatically changing this longstanding policy for energy commodities.
    (3)The Futures Market Is Unique Since Bu~/ers Offset Sellers, Obviating the Need for
    Position Limit Restrictions.
    The proposed position limits are superfluous because futures markets by their nature possess
    a fundamental balance not present in other markets. Commodities in futures markets do not have a
    finite number of contracts. If demand exists on either side of a future, another party can easily meet
    the other side of that demand, thereby quickly increasing or decreasing the open interest in that
    contract.
    As a result the futures markets are essentially balanced - for every long there is an equal
    offsetting short position and for every short there is an equal offsetting long position. When cleared
    through the U.S. futures exchanges, the profits from one side are in equilibrium in every instance to
    the losses incurred by the other. Since losses are offset by gains, money is simply transferred from
    one account to the other and there is no net loss of wealth in either bull or bear markets.
    Accordingly, when speculators win, hedgers lose, and when hedgers win, speculators must lose.
    (4)The Proposed Regulations Encumber the Free Market and Break Down the
    Efficiency of the Price Discovery Mechanism.
    The futures exchanges allow for the creation of a free marketplace where willing buyers and
    willing sellers can come together to discover the price of the commodity that they are trading. Each
    time willing participants meet to buy and sell the commodities, they are engaging in the process of
    i0
    Laura Campbell, Assistant Manager of Energy Resources, Memphis Light, Gas & Water, on behalf of The
    American Public Gas Association,
    Testimony before the Commodity Futures Trading Commission
    (Jul. 28, 2009),
    online at
    ~://www.ct'tc.
    ~!.i;4~)2newsroomidocuments/fileihearil~%_~}~)__gamRbel !.Ddf.
    410-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    constantly discovered in an open and transparent manner. However, onerous regulatory constraints
    imposed on market participants will impede them from transacting freely. As explained further
    below, these constraints are unusually onerous because, they significantly interfere with risk
    offloading, price discovery, and diversification. The inevitable result will be less efficient markets
    and therefore more volatile commodity prices.
    (5)The Proposed Position Limits Will Hinder the Ability of Individuals and Corporate
    Hedgers to Offload Risks.
    A chief objective of the futures market is to provide individuals and companies who
    maintain price risk in their day-to-day business activities a place to offset those risks via hedging
    transactions. For example, the futures markets allows grain handlers to make commitments to buy
    or sell grain from and to their clients for months or years into the future. A deep and liquid futures
    market functions as a surrogate buyer or seller until an actual client can be found. Without the
    futures markets, .the merchandisers would have no place to allay their risks of ownership on the long
    side, or to make a short position~for a client .who needs a long-dated sale. The futures markets exist
    to allow hedgers to hedge, a function only robust futures markets can accomplish.
    (6)Position Limits Proposed by the CFTC Will Directly Inhibit Speculators' Ability to
    Take a View on Prices, Either Upwards or Downwards, and Consequently Will Severely
    Damage the Price Discovery Mechanism That Is the Modern Futures Market.
    The futures markets also exist to allow speculators a forum to take a view on prices.
    Speculators are permitted to place their own money at risk if they so choose, and in the process of
    speculating (both long and short) they Create liquidity that allows hedgers to easily hedge and the
    price of the underlying contract to be properly "discovered." But the proposed position limits, if
    passed, will prevent firms that are supposedly hedgers to take any positions other than perfect hedge
    positions and simultaneously prevent speculators from taking short positions unless they have a
    direct price risk of their own.
    As a consequence, the proposed limits will significantly diminish liquidity, the lifeblood of
    efficient futures markets. If hedgers lose much of their ability to hedge, the currently transparent
    price discovery process will become opaque as speculators move to over-the-counter ("OTC") and
    overseas markets. Energy prices, rather than being continuously discovered by participants with
    real interests in the commodity in question and by speculators who wish to take an interest in that
    same commodity, each hoping to profit over the other, thereby promoting the price discovery
    function of the market itself, will be "skewed" by artificial and arbitrary constraints. U.S. futures
    markets, their efficiency crippled, will see significant thinning and increased volatility.
    (7)Passive Index-Tracking Funds Should Be Exempt from Any Proposed and Existin~
    Position Limits Since These Passive Investors (1) Do Not Impact the Supply and Demand of
    Commodities, (2) Are Heavy Net Sellers of Nearby Futures Contracts, (3) Do Not Speculate
    on Price Movements, and (4) Increase the Stability of the Markets.
    It is a fundamental principle of the futures market that prices are set in the cash market by
    supply and demand for the actual physical commodities. However, passive index funds do not
    5consume any commodities.
    i0-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    Further, passive index funds apply
    zero
    net buying pressure across the commodity term
    structure. As passive index funds cannot and do not hold positions into the delivery month, the
    primary market activity in which these unique market participants engage is the simple "rolling" of
    futures as they approach the spot month. This "rolling" occurs by selling nearby contracts and
    simultaneously buying an equal dollar amount of a more deferred contract. As the nexus of the cash
    and the futures market (at the near end of the futures curve), passive index funds are heavy net
    sellers as they sell their nearby current futures holdings in order to roll into more distant futures
    positions. Thus as futures contracts become deliverable to and converge with the physical market,
    index funds are no longer involved in those contracts and have no effect on the physical price
    determination process.
    Additionally, passive index funds create a more liquid and efficient futures market for
    hedgers and speculators alike. Passive index tracking funds own futures contracts for the purpose
    of providing their underlying investors with portfolio diversification and inflation hedging. They do
    not take positions, short or long, in anticipation of future price movements. Often, the passive funds
    participate in illiquid contracts, thereby bringing liquidity where none existed.
    Finally, passive index funds accomplish the same ends at which the Proposal aims. The
    Commission seeks to balance and calm the markets, but the markets are already more balanced and
    calmer because of the activities of passive index funds. They permit the small investor to gain
    access to and profit from the markets without suffering large risk. The funds are highly regulated,
    highly transparent, and fundamentally conservative in approach: they seek incremental growth and
    minimal loss through passive investing. In this fashion, the introduction of the small investor via
    passive index funds increases the market's capacity for risk-sharing.
    Thus, the Commission's proposed rules should encourage, not limit, increased participation
    by index funds.
    (8)Compliance with the Proposed Aggregation Rule Would Be Severely Costly and
    Perhaps Impossible.
    The Proposal states that the proposed regulations "would aggregate positions in accounts at
    both the account owner and controller levels." Under this expanded scope, "eligible entities (such
    as mutual funds, commodity pool operators, and commodity trading advisors) and futures
    commission merchants will not be permitted to disaggregate positions pursuant to the independent
    account controller framework established in part 150 of the Commission's regulations." In other
    words, a firm will be obliged to aggregate positions across various divisions, no matter how
    numerous, how distant, or how independent those divisions may be. Current software would
    require radical reconfiguring, at great cost, to attempt to record and compile these various activities
    fast enough to satisfy the proposed regulation. Nor is it certain such an attempt would succeed.
    11
    If the level of inventories rose with index investment, then, as Bob Greer put it on page 2 of his paper, cited
    supra
    page 3:
    the developed world would not be hostage to the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Count~'ies (OPEC).
    Any time we needed to increase crude inventories, we [could] merely.., bring in more indexers, and the
    inventory would appear. In fact, the explanation for inventory levels of any commodity is much simpler. If, in
    the cash markets, production exceeds demand, inventories will rise. Otherwise, they will fall.
    610-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    series ofi~ositions-each near a proposed outer bound position limit with~)ut aggregation, may not be
    appropriate." This speculative statement begs the question whether the Proposal can be justified.
    Without a solid basis, the CFTC should not impose so costly a requirement.
    Moreover, while the Commission has not offered evidence of the existence or likelihood of
    coordination among traders, the proposed solution will actually make such coordination more
    likely. Firms do not now have the software in place to coordinate the trading activities of their
    diverse and separate divisions. But the proposed regulation will require them to develop this
    software. In other words, while coordination among divisions does not appear to exist at present,
    the "solution" may facilitate such coordination. ' '
    (9) Aggregation Rules Should Be Modernized.
    The Proposal does not address the crucial issue of aggregation of energy and other
    commodity positions amongst entities that are under common control. The Commission should
    adopt an aggregation rule that is responsive to the legitimate trading and risk management needs of
    financial
    holding companies that have numerous affiliates and trading desks, each of which
    independently trade in the futures markets. The CPOs of commodity pools and index-tracking
    commodity pools, as well as issuers of commodity-indexed notes, are often separate business units
    of a multifaceted financial institution that have implemented appropriate barriers between the units.
    We encourage the Commission to consider adopting a responsible aggregation rule for a
    multifaceted financial institution. In this regard, we recommend that the Commission amend
    Regulation 150.3 (a)(5) (or add a new section to proposed part 151) to responsibly disaggregate a
    financial
    holding company's affiliates' positions, as follows.
    "Proposed Rule 150.3(a)(5) - Aggregation Exemption for Financial Institutions
    (a)
    Positions which may exceed limits. The position limits set forth in § 150.2 and § 151.2 of
    this part may be exceeded to the extent such positions are:
    (5)
    Financial Institution.
    (i)
    Carried by (a) an Independent Trading Unit (as defined herein) of a financial
    institution (as defined in section 1 a(15) of the Act) in the separate account or
    accounts of the financial institution controlled by an Independent Trading Unit of the
    financial
    institution or (b) any commodity pool organized as a separate legal entity or
    separate series of a separate legal entity where trading is controlled by such
    Independent Trading Unit, in each case where each Independent Trading Unit of the
    financial
    institution has, and enforces, written procedures to preclude other
    Independent Trading Units from having lcnowledge of, gaining access to, or
    receiving data about, trades of the other ("Disaggregation Procedures"). Such
    Disaggregation Procedures must include document routing and other procedures or
    security arrangements, including separate physical locations, which would
    maintain
    the independence of their activities;
    provided however,
    that such Disaggregation
    Procedures may provide for the disclosure of information which is reasonably
    necessary for a financial institution to maintain the level of control consistent with its
    fiduciary responsibilities and necessary to fulfill its duty to supervise diligently the
    trading done on its behalf or through the Independent Trading Units, including(ii)
    10-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    and supervisory)e~sonn~l that may be common to all Independent Trading Units.
    The financial institution must file with the Commission a notice of eligibility that:
    (a)
    describes and confirms the implementation of the Disaggregation
    Procedures;
    (b)
    (c)
    (d)
    (e)
    designates an office of the financial institution responsible to
    coordinate the Disaggregation Procedures;
    provides an organizational chart that includes the name, main
    business address, main business telephone number, main facsimile
    number and main email address of the financial institution, each
    Independent Trading Unit, and if applicable, any separate legal entity
    whose trading is controlled by such Independent Trading Unit;
    provides the names of pertinent staff of each Independent Trading
    Unit (trading, operations, compliance, clerical, and risk management)
    and their work locations;
    provides a description of all information sharing systems, bulletin
    boards, and common email addresses;
    (g)
    (h)
    provides an explanation of the financial institution's risk management
    system and staff structure and a description of the overall structure
    and operations of the relevant staff;
    provides an explanation of how and to whom the trade data and
    position information is distributed for each Independent Trading Unit,
    including which officers receive reports for all Independent Trading
    Units and their respective titles; and
    is signed by a representative duly authorized to bind the financial
    institution.
    As used in this rule, the term "Independent Trading Unit" means a branch, office,
    profit center, affiliated commodity pool operator, passive commodity pool tracking
    an index, or affiliate of the financial institution that complies with the Disaggregation
    Procedures and is listed in the notice of eligibility.
    The notice of eligibility will be effective upon filing, provided the notice is
    materially complete. The notice of eligibility must be refiled within 45 days of
    January 1 of each year following the initial filing."
    B.
    Responses to Commission's Questions.
    In response to several of the questions posed in Appendix A, below are the questions and
    our responses.10-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    reporting markets necessary to "diminish, eliminate, or prevent" the burdens on interstate commerce
    that may result ~om position concentrations in such contracts?
    Response.
    No, it is not necessary for the Commission (a) to apply federal speculative
    position limits concurrently with existing exchange-set position limits and position accountability
    requirements or (b) to create an aggregate set of limits that would apply to similar futures contracts
    across markets. The fear of "burdens on interstate commerce" is misplaced. Greater speculative
    investment does not lead to inflated prices or higher volatility. As such, the suggested regulations
    would not serve their declared purpose.
    As explained in detail in the general comments above, the Proposal contains no empirical
    evidence of the supposed connection between increased speculation and higher prices or volatility.
    Furthermore, the data available from other sources, including the CFTC's own research, does not
    support such a connection. Without any cause-and-effect relationship, the proposed regulations will
    not prevent price spikes. Rather, just as contracts in the agricultural markets suffered unusually
    high prices in 2007-08 in the face of position limits, prices will rise and fall based on factors other
    than those addressed by the Proposal.
    Because the solution devised is unnecessary and ineffectual, it will succeed only in
    constraining a popular investment vehicle that improves the stability of the futures markets.
    Question
    2. Are there methods other than Federal speculative position limits that should
    be utilized to diminish, eliminate, or prevent such burdens?
    Response.
    The Commission's aggregation regime must be modernized to prudently
    apply the limits to passive index-tracking CPOs who use the futures markets for legitimate risk
    management purposes, in a manner that does not penalize those CPOs who operate multiple
    commodity pools, each a separate legal entity, each having its own public investor beneficial
    owners, each tracking a different index. Imposing Federal speculative position limits without also
    adopting a realistic aggregation policy that permits responsible traders, such as a regulated CPO, to
    trade in these markets without the positions in one of its pools being aggregated with those of its
    other pools, will decrease liquidity and impair price discovery, causing pools to move their trading
    to foreign markets. The Commission should adopt an aggregation rule that disaggregates the
    positions of highly regulated passive index-tracking commodity pools from other pools that either
    (a) are operated by the same CPO or (b) track the same index, where there is either no common
    control or no common ownership among the investors that own 10% or more of the pools.
    Additionally, rather than imposing strict limits, the Commission should consider adopting
    "position accountability" standards similar to those administered by futures exchanges as required
    under Appendix B to Part 38 of the Commission's regulations. Position accountability, rather than
    position limits, would permit the Commission to require traders who own or control positions in
    excess of certain thresholds to provide the Commission, upon request, with information regarding
    the nature of the positions, hedging needs, and the trading strategy to enable the Commission to
    determine at that time the appropriate course of action, rather than arbitrarily imposing limits on all
    traders.
    Finally, if the Commission does adopt Federal speculative position limits, the different
    exchanges should either withdraw their position accountability and position limits regimes in
    9will apply across exchanges.
    i0-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    Question 3. How should the Commission evaluate the potential effect of Federal
    speculative position limits on the liquidity, market efficiency and price discovery capabilities of
    referenced energy contracts in determining whether to establish position limits for such contracts?
    Response.
    The exchanges currently set position limits for the last three trading days
    before the delivery period and accountability levels for energy commodities. If Federal position
    limits replace or supersede exchange-set accountability levels for energy and other commodities of
    finite supply, the integrity of the price discovery process will be compromised. Fixing a position
    limit solely for U.S. energy futures trading will cause traders seeking additional commodity price
    exposure to shift to foreign exchanges or OTC markets, thus avoiding exposure to the impact of the
    proposed rules. As more market participants shift to these other, less transparent markets, the focal
    point for price discovery will also shift.
    Question 4. Under the class approach to grouping contracts as discussed herein, how
    should contracts that do not cash settle to the price of a single contract, but settle to the average
    price of a sub-group of contracts within a class be treated during the spot month for the purposes of
    enforcing the proposed speculative position limits?
    Response.
    These should also be treated as separate given different settlement prices.
    Question 5. Under proposed regulation 151.2(b)(1)(i), the Commission would establish
    an all-months-combined aggregate position limit equal to 10% of the average combined futures and
    option contract open interest aggregated across all reporting markets for the most recent calendar
    year up to 25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase of 2.5% of open interest thereafter. As an
    alternative to this approach to an all-months-combined aggregate position limit, the Commission
    requests comment on whether an additional increment with a marginal increase larger than 2.5%
    ~
    would be adequate to prevent excessive speculation in the referenced energy contracts. An
    additional increment would permit traders to hold larger positions relative to total open positions in
    the referenced energy contracts, in comparison to the proposed formula. For example, the
    Commission could fix the all-months-combined aggregate position limit at 10% of the prior year's
    average open interest up to 25,000 contracts, with a marginal increase of 5% up to 300,000
    contracts and a marginal increase of 2.5% thereafter. Assuming the prior year's average open
    interest equaled 300,000 contracts, an all-months-combined aggregate position limit would be fixed
    at 9,400 contracts under the proposed rule and 16,300 contracts under the alternative.
    Response.
    Under the proposed rules, the all-month limit ("AML") for each of the four
    energy commodities approaches 2.5% of open interest as open interest increases. Thus the rationale
    behind the 25,000 threshold is weak and needlessly complex.
    A simpler solution would be to fix the percentage of open interest. As open interest grows,
    so does the AML. We think the rule for passive speculators should be 10% (thus requiring at
    minimum 10 aggregators in the market) and for non-aggregators/speculators it should be 5% (thus
    requiring at minimum 20 speculators in the market). Given the size of the energy markets (large
    number of participants) the CFTC's concerns should be addressed by these limits. (We note that
    each of the limits we propose are as arbitrary as the 2.5% limit and the 25k OI threshold proposed
    by the CFTC.)
    1010-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    moderating the limit levels proposed by the Commission? In this connection, the Commission notes
    that current regulation 150.5(c) states contract markets may adjust their speculative limit levels
    "based on position sizes customarily held by speculative traders on the contract market, which shall
    not be extraordinarily large relative to total open positions in the contract..."
    Response.
    No, speculative limits should not be based on position sizes customarily held
    by speculative traders in that contract market. The futures market is not a "one size fits all" market.
    Speculators in the futures markets have vastly divergent trading strategies and goals. Some
    speculators invest based on their view of future market movements. Others, such as passively
    managed index tracking ETFs, invest to provide their underlying investors with access to the
    markets without the inherent complexities and risks of directly investing in futures (e.g., margin
    requirements, clearing issues, diversification, and position limit monitoring). Given the diversity of
    participants, basing AML on the customary size of speculators will serve to permit a more
    homogenous set of market participants, which could potentially lead to less liquid and more volatile
    markets.
    Question 7. Reporting markets that list referenced energy contracts, as defined by the
    proposed regulations, would continue to be responsible for maintaining their own position limits (so
    long as they are not higher than the limits fixed by the Commission) or position accountability rules.
    The Commission seeks comment on whether it should issue acceptable practices that adopt formal
    guidelines and procedures for implementing position accountability rules.
    Response.
    The Commission's speculative position limits should preempt self-regulatory
    organization ("SRO") accountability limits. Currently, in the absence of speculative limits in the
    energy complex, accountability limits are imposed by SROs to ensure that no single market
    participant achieves a large percentage of the open interest in a pa1"dcular contract. Should position
    limits rooted in open interest be imposed by the CFTC, accountability limits would be redundant (as
    they would serve the same function as the speculative limits), (2) add costs to all parties (including
    CFTC, SROs, investors, CTAs, CPOs), and (3) add unnecessary regulatory complexity.
    Position accountability rules and position limits maintained by the exchanges should be
    explicitly limited to speculative positions. Positions traded for risk management purposes in respect
    of a passive index-tracking fund should be explicitly excluded from these requirements.
    Question 10. The Commission's proposed part 151 regulations for referenced energy
    contracts would set forth a comprehensive regime of position limit, exemption, and aggregation
    requirements that would operate separately from the current position limit, exemption, and
    aggregation requirements for agricultural contracts set forth in part 150 of the Commission's
    regulations. While proposed part 151 borrows many features of part 150, there are notable
    distinctions between the two, including their methods of position limit calculation and treatment of
    positions held by swap dealers. The Commission seeks comment on what, if any, of the distinctive
    features of the position limit framework proposed herein, such as aggregate position limits and the
    swap dealer limited risk management exemption, should be applied to the agricultural commodities
    listed in part 150 of the Commission's regulations.
    Response.
    In a departure from the current rule 150.3(a)(4) aggregation regime for
    agricultural products, commodity pool operators, mutual funds and certain CFTC registrants (each
    an "eligible entity") would not be permitted to disaggregate energy positions that are traded on their
    1110-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    position~ traded by IACs for collective inv~stmen~ vehicles a~e &aggregated under)art 150. In
    departing from this established procedure, under the Proposal, energy position limits would be
    applied to all positions in which a person has a direct or indirect ownership of 10% or greater, or
    25% or greater in a commodity pool.
    The Proposal would aggregate the positions in accounts in which any person has an
    ownership or equity interest of 10% or more, or with respect to which such person controls the
    trading. As a result, the Proposal would aggregate positions in accounts at both the account owner
    and control level for energy commodities, in addition to eliminating the IAC exemption for position
    limits that currently exists in Regulation 150.3(a)(4). With respect to commodity pools, energy
    position limits would be applied to all positions in which any person has a direct or indirect
    ownership or equity interest of 10% or greater, subject to an exemption for a.passive limited partner
    or shareholder ("pool participant") having less than a 25% ownership interest of a commodity pool.
    Under proposed rule 150.4(b), the pool participant need not aggregate the pool's energy positions
    with its other positions. We urge the Commission to clarify that although a pool participant having
    greater than 25% ownership of a commodity pool must aggregate the pool's energy positions with
    the pool participant's positions, proposed rule 150.4(b) is not intended to require the commodity
    pool to aggregate the participant's energy positions with those of the pool, i.e., one,way aggregation
    is the intent of the Proposal. Requiring a commodity pool to aggregate its pool participant's
    positions with those of the pool would result in a pool's trading ability being limited by the
    independent trading of its pool participants whom it does not control, and create an ongoing
    unnecessary due diligence and operational burden for CPOs.
    We urge the CFTC to retain the IAC exemption as it currently exists in Regulation
    150.3(a)(4) and its applicability to energy commodities. The IAC exemption is premised on the fact
    that accounts that are under separate management need not be aggregated because they have no
    combined effect on the market. The elimination of the IAC exemption is unnecessary and will be
    disruptive to a wide variety of market participants that have relied upon the exemption to operate
    efficiently in the commodity markets.
    The Proposal will also require holding company structures that have separate business units
    trading for various proprietary and customer accounts to aggregate their holdings across their
    various business units. The Proposal is not operationally feasible for large financial institutions and
    will have the unintended consequence of requiring organizations that have not shared information in
    the past to disclose their positions to other independent business units.12
    Question 12. As discussed previously, the Commission has followed a policy since 2008 of
    conditioning FBOT no-action relief on the requirement that FBOTs with contracts that link to
    CFTC-regulated contracts have position limits that are comparable to the position limits applicable
    to CFTC-regulated contracts. If the Commission adopts the proposed rulemaldng, should it
    continue, or modify in any way, this policy to address FBOT contracts that would be linked to any
    referenced energy contract as defined by the proposed regulations?
    The Proposal is also inconsistent with the approach taken by the SEC under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934.
    The SEC permits the parent holding company of qualified institutional investors to disaggregate the holdings of its
    various business units if there are appropriate informational barriers between the business units for purposes of
    Section 13(d) and (g) and Section 16(a) reporting requirements.
    See
    Amendments to Beneficial Ownership
    Reporting Requirements, Exchange Act Release No. 34-39538, 63 Fed. Reg. 2854, at 2857-8 (Jan. 12, 1998).
    1210-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    regulated contracts. FBOT contracts generally have different terms and characteristics even if the
    underlier is similar to a CFTC-regulated contract.
    Question 13. The Commission notes that Congress is currently considering legislation that
    would revise the Commission's section 4a(a) position limit authority to extend beyond positions in
    reporting market contracts to reach positions in OTC derivative instruments and FBOT contracts.
    Under some of these revisions, the Commission would be authorized to set limits for positions held
    in OTC derivative instruments and FBOT contracts. The Commission seeks comment on how it
    should take this pending legislation into account in proposing Federal speculative position limits.
    Response.
    We recommend that the Commission wait until final OTC derivatives
    legislation, such as Title III of H.R. 4173, is enacted betbre proposing Federal speculative position
    limits. As the final legislation may differ from the pending legislation, it may be futile at this time
    to anticipate how to coordinate exchange-traded futures limits with OTC derivatives position limits.
    Question 14. Under proposed regulation 151.2, the Commission would set spot-month and
    all-months-combined position limits annually.
    b.
    Should the Commission establish, by using a rolling-average of open interest instead
    of a simple average for example, all-months-combined position limits on a more frequent basis? If
    so, what reasons would support such action?
    Response.
    No, the Commission should not make the rules unnecessarily complex.
    Complex rules that are not warranted by market conditions will cause traders to seek other markets
    outside of the U.S. Rolling averages or more frequent averages are an extreme response to what
    appears to be a phantom problem.
    Question 15. Concerns have been raised about the impact of large, passive, and
    unleveraged long-only positions on the futures markets. Instead of using the futures markets for
    risk transference, traders that own such positions treat commodity futures contracts as distinct assets
    that can be held for an appreciable duration. This notice of rulemaking does not propose regulations
    that would categorize such positions for the purpose of applying different regulatory standards.
    Rather, the owners of such positions are treated as other investors that would be subject to the
    proposed speculative position limits.
    Response.
    Passive, unleveraged long-only index-tracking trading strategies used by
    many publicly-traded commodity pools, as well as by index tracking pools that are leveraged and/or
    also take short positions (each a "Passive Pool"), can be distinguished from actively managed
    commodity pools. A Passive Pool is not a "speculator" within the intent of Commission Regulation
    1.3(z). A Passive Pool's investment objective is simply to track an index over time, regardless of
    whether the index is rising, falling or flat. To that end, a Passive Pool acquires long futures
    positions in the commodities making up the underlying index. Because a Passive Pool is not an
    actively managed pool, it does not utilize a discretionary trading program or any other investment or
    trading methodology.
    Regulation 1.3 (z) provides in relevant part that hedging transactions "are economically
    appropriate to the reduction of risks in the conduct and management of a commercial enterprise." A
    Passive Pool's only objective is to track the underlying index over time (through acquiring long
    futures positions), using a nondiscretionary methodology. A Passive Pool should be viewed as
    1310-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    futures positions in the underlying index commodities, with no intent to speculate in the futures
    market, therefore presenting no danger of excessive speculation that may cause harmful fluctuations
    in commodity prices.
    Under Section 4a(c) of the CEA, the Commission must exempt "bona fide hedging
    transactions" from its position limits. Yet this requirement does not forbid other exemptions as
    well. The CEA gives the Commission flexibility in this area to mold appropriate exemptions for
    traders found not to have engaged in commodity speculation. The Commission could adopt an
    exemption from speculative position limits for Passive Pools.
    The Commission staff granted, but then three years later rescinded, no-action relief to two
    passive long index-based funds from speculative position limits on certain agricultural
    commodities.
    See
    CFTC Letter 06-09 (April 19, 2006); CFTC Letter 06-19 (September 6, 2006).
    The no-action letters provide guidance in establishing an exemption for Passive Pools. In 2009, the
    Commission staff affirmatively determined that these funds "represented a legitimate and
    potentially useful investment strategy." 74 Federal Register 12282 (CFTC, March 24, 2009), at
    footnote 15.
    As stated in the no-action letters, Passive Pools include the following attributes: (i) passive
    tracking of a benchmark; (ii) excess positions not affecting the spot month futures contract;
    (iii) high level of transparency; (iv) extensive federal and self-regulatory oversight; and (v) lack of
    price exposure to the fund.
    See
    CFTC Letter 06-09 at 4; CFTC Letter 06-19 at 5-6.
    These unique features of Passive Pools allow them to actively participate in the commodity
    futures market while still providing substantial protections and full disclosure to market participants
    and the investing public. Their activities do not cause the concerns that Federal position limits are
    intended to address. Additionally, limiting the ability of Passive Pools to trade in the futures
    markets will: (i) expose retail passive investor customers to bilateral credit risks; (ii) increase price
    volatility and reduce liquidity; and (iii) force more retail customers to access the futures markets
    directly. We believe that the Commission should codify rules exempting Passive Pools from
    speculative position limits or adopt a separate position limits exemption for Passive Pools.
    traders?
    Should the Commission propose regulations to limit the positions of passive long
    Response.
    Notwithstanding the public hearings conducted in 2009 by the Commission,
    there is no published empirical data evidencing that trading by passive long traders has caused any
    harmful energy price movements, as discussed in the general comments above.
    13
    We believe that
    the Commission does not need to issue explicit regulations to limit positions of passive long traders
    such as Passive Pools, as Passive Pools are not traditional speculators. The Commission should
    recognize the index-tracking strategies of passive long traders, as opposed to' actively managed
    trading strategies. Because a Passive Pool long trader that tracks an index cannot form the intent to
    manipulate the market or cause harmful fluctuations in commodity prices, and because it tracks an
    13
    To the contrary, passive investors may have beneficial effects on futures markets, by decreasing volatility and
    improving non-spot month liquidity.
    See
    Scott Irwin, Dwight Sanders, Robert Merrin,
    Devil or Angel? The Role of
    Speculation in the Recent Commodity Price Boom (and BusO,
    JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL AND APPLIED
    ECONOMICS, Vol. 41, No. 02 (Aug. 2009),
    online at
    ~url.umn.edui53083.
    See also
    Philip K. Verleger,
    Notes at the Margin
    (Jan. 11, 2010),
    online at
    htt~p)(/~ymqqgeriic,com/nam t 001 I
    1410-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    management in the pool, rather than. a strict numerical limit. Larger Passive Pools should have
    higher limits. Prior actions by the Commission in respect of passive long traders have reportedly
    caused one large pool to reduce its futures holdings and utilize more expensive and less transparent
    OTC derivatives as an alternative, also resulting in potentially increased tracking errors relative to
    the benchmark futures prices.
    See
    "UNG Fund Cuts Natgas Position Due to CFTC Moves"
    (Reuters, July 29, 2009). Presumably, the OTC swap dealer used by the pool will in turn simply
    hedge its exposure through the use of futures, resulting in the same positions' being traded, albeit by
    the dealer rather than the pool. To avoid adversely affecting a pool's public retail investors, we
    recommend that the Commission refrain from adopting constrictive, arbitrary position limits for
    passive long traders. We encourage the Commission to create an exemptive process for passive
    long traders similar to the proposed swap dealer risk management exemption.
    b.
    If so, what criteria should the Commission employ to identify and define such traders
    and positions?
    Response.
    Most Passive Pools are passive long traders, as is evident from a review of
    their disclosure documents. The Commission could consider having such Pools file a certificate
    with the Commission confirming their status as an "Index-tracking Exchange-traded Pool (or
    ITETP)," and apply speculative position limit and aggregation rules and exemptions applicable to
    these uniquely transparent and highly regulated collective investment vehicles.
    e.
    Assuming that passive long traders can properly be identified and defined, how and
    to what extent should the Commission limit their participation in the futures markets?
    Response.
    Passive long traders, such as Passive Pools, should be permitted to trade
    pursuant to a "passive long trading exemption" similar to the Commission's proposed swap dealer
    risk management exemption, requiring appropriate filing with the Commission. This will facilitate
    liquidity in the markets rather than force these traders to seek alternatives such as OTC swap
    transactions or foreign futures markets.
    d.
    If passive long positions should be limited in the aggregate, would it be feasible for
    the Commission to apportion market space amongst various traders that wish to establish passive
    long positions?
    Response.
    fund's own merits.
    No. Market space should be apportioned to each fund according to each
    e.
    What unintended consequences are likely to result from the Commission's
    implementation of passive long position limits?
    Response.
    Such unintended consequences include (a) removing from the market a
    significant source of liquidity, (b) disenfranchising the thousands of public retail investors who
    invest in Passive Pools as a mechanism to prudently access these markets as a diversification and
    hedging tool, (c) preventing the passive long trader's affiliated commodity pools, if subject to
    aggregation, from using the futures markets, (d) causing these traders to utilize OTC derivatives and
    foreign markets as alternatives, which are less transparent and less regulated markets, (e) increasing
    price volatility and distortion of price discovery signals and (f) leaving foreign markets as the focal
    points for commodity price discovery.
    1510-002
    COMMENT
    CL-02713
    index, and contracts of the same class are intended to be simple definitions tfiat readily identify the"
    affected contracts through an objective and administerial process without relying on the
    Commission's exercise of discretion.
    e.
    Should diversified commodity indexes be defined with greater particularity?
    Response.
    "Diversified" should mean more than four underlying contracts, none of
    whose target index base weights is greater than 50% of the fund's index.
    DBCS thanks the Commission for the opportunity to submit this comment letter. Please do
    not hesitate to contact the undersigned or our outside counsel, Michael Sackheim of Sidley Austin
    LLP at (212) 839-5503 if you would like to discuss our comments.
    Respectfully submitted,
    Michael S. Saclcheim
    Hans Ephraimson, Chief Executive Officer
    NY1 7223698v.i0
    16